Ben Mathew Economics
  • Home
  • Bio
  • Blog
  • Recommended
  • Mailing List
  • Contact

Obamacare

12/31/2013

0 Comments

 
John Cochrane of the University of Chicago Booth School of Business had a great op-ed in the WSJ about the Affordable Care Act, a.k.a. Obamacare. I have been meaning to do a post on Obamacare for a while. I haven't studied the issue in much depth, but in general I've been supportive because the previous system was clearly broken. My take was that there was a market failure because of the problematic nature of insurance markets (moral hazard and adverse selection), and we needed some sort of intervention. Here's what I saw as broken with the old system:

(1) Lots of people were uninsured. They were forced to show up at hospital ERs and then not pay. Taxpayers ended up paying for this backdoor insurance anyway. It was an expensive and inefficient kind of insurance that placed a lot of unnecessary stress on both the uninsured and the taxpayers.

(2) Even people with insurance were not truly insured. Everyone was just one job loss and one chronic condition away from becoming uninsured because (a) insurance was tied to jobs and (b) insurers could discriminate on the basis of pre-existing conditions.

(3) Medical costs were increasing in a way that just didn't make any sense to me.

Obamacare requires everyone to purchase health insurance (providing subsidies for those who can't afford it) and prohibit insurers from discriminating on the basis of pre-existing conditions. I thought that both these moves were important steps in the right direction. The website fiasco highlighted the government's inability to do anything right, but that didn't bother me so much because I felt that the heart of Obamacare was really a private health insurance market operating under new rules--not a centralized government-administed insurance program that most Obamacare opponents make it out to be.

But Cochrane gives me some food for thought. He claims that the previous system was broken because insurance was tied to jobs:
Health insurance should be individual, portable across jobs, states and providers; lifelong and guaranteed-renewable, meaning you have the right to continue with no unexpected increase in premiums if you get sick. Insurance should protect wealth against large, unforeseen, necessary expenses, rather than be a wildly inefficient payment plan for routine expenses.

People want to buy this insurance, and companies want to sell it. It would be far cheaper, and would solve the pre-existing conditions problem. We do not have such health insurance only because it was regulated out of existence. Businesses cannot establish or contribute to portable individual policies, or employees would have to pay taxes. So businesses only offer group plans. Knowing they will abandon individual insurance when they get a job, and without cross-state portability, there is little reason for young people to invest in lifelong, portable health insurance.
Seems obvious to me now, but I hadn't linked the absence of lifelong guaranteed-renewable health insurance to the dysfunctional rules tying health insurance to jobs. I am more optimistic now that deregulating the health insurance marketplace free will solve many of the problems facing our healthcare system, and might well be a better alternative to the Obamacare. But I would still keep the Obamacare requirements that everyone has to buy insurance and that insurers can't discriminate on the basis of pre-existing conditions.
0 Comments

Publisher Economics

12/22/2013

2 Comments

 
The New York Times ran an opinion piece, Triumph of the English Major, by book editor and English major, Gerald Howard. While working for Penguin Books in the early '80s, Howard reissued "two early novels by the fine writer Alice Adams." The project delivered a 7 percent return, and the bean counters weren't happy.
So there I was in our C.F.O.’s office with a P. & L. that just eked out a 7 percent return. He looked at that piece of paper dubiously. He looked at me dubiously. I made some weak noises about literary excellence, backlist sales, commitment to authors. He continued to look at me dubiously. Then, with that wry and sad expression with which financial people have regarded liberal arts people since at least the invention of movable type and perhaps even written language, he signed off on my shortfallen P. & L. and said to me, “You know, we could make more money by just putting this advance into a certificate of deposit.”

I produced the properly crestfallen face because I knew he was right. Inflation was rampant and C.D.’s were paying 10 percent per annum or more. What a drag I was on the corporation. But I grabbed the P. & L. before he could have second thoughts, thanked him and backed out of his office.

However, as I went back to my office I experienced an instance of what the French call “stair wit.” I thought, wait a minute, I am putting that $7,500 to work. It’s an investment. The chain of activity I am putting in motion will give work to printers and shippers. It will provide bookstores (there were still bookstores) with tangible goods to sell at a profit. The revenue from those sales will help to pay my salary, my colleagues’ salaries, even our C.F.O.’s salary. Alice Adams will have some thousands of dollars in her pocket — maybe to invest in a C.D. All this and a few thousand people fewer than I put down on the P. & L. (I’d lied, of course) will have bought and enjoyed two excellent novels that deserved to be in print.

Whereas if we’d just put that money in the hands of a bank, they would just ... well, I was pretty hazy on what a bank would actually do with that money, but my general sense was that it would sit there in a vault microbially propagating itself and what good would that do anybody? Economically I was putting my shoulder — or Penguin’s shoulder — to the wheel! I came away with the conviction that I wasn’t useless anymore.
Two problems with this analysis:

First, whiles it's true that t
he $7,500 investment in reissuing Alice Adams novels gives work to printers, shippers, etc. if he had just ordered $7,500 worth of ice cream for the whole office, it would have generated work for dairy farmers, ice cream shops, etc.. So which is better? Prices guide you. A high rate of return from an investment (a high price for your output) is a signal that your investment is going towards the things that society values. If you get a 7 percent rate of return from Alice Adams and a 10 percent return from Stephen King, then the printers and shippers you had "given work to" printing and shipping Alice Adams should have been printing and shipping Stephen King instead. Henry Hazlitt's Economics in One Lesson debunks many common fallacies of this variety.

Second, $7,500 in the hands of a bank does not "sit there in a vault microbially propagating itself." It would have been lent to someone else to invest is some other venture--maybe printing and shipping Stephen King.
Chapter 19 of Economics covers how banks work.

I wish the definition of "liberal arts" included economics.

2 Comments

What is a Bubble?

12/20/2013

0 Comments

 
When the price of an asset (stocks, bonds, real estate, tulips, whatever) is driven up beyond "reason", we say it's a bubble. This year's economics Nobel was awarded to finance professors (Eugene Fama of Chicago, Bob Shiller of Yale, and my old macro prof, Lars Hansen of Chicago). Fama and Shiller famously disagree on how "rational" financial markets--and therefore asset prices--are. Fama falls in the rational camp, whereas Shiller writes books titled Irrational Exuberance, Animal Spirits, and such.

After winning the Nobel Prize, Fama said something to the effect that he doesn't know what bubble is and it's all meaningless.

To which
Shiller said "
What is a bubble? You [Gene Fama] said nobody defines it. So I will define it. A speculative bubble is a fad. People get excited sometimes. Too excited... Prices start going up, they start talking, the newspapers start writing about it, more and more people pile in to a market and they push prices up more and it goes on for a while. eventually it breaks and the bubble bursts."

To which John Cochrane, Fama's colleague at Chicago, said "
That's not a "definition." That's an explanation, a theory. A definition tells you in an operational way what pattern in the data describes "bubble." An explanation is a theory that predicts the defined phenomenon."

About a year ago, a family friend had e-mailed me asking what exactly bubbles are.  Our e-mail exchange contains my view of what a bubble is:

_________________
Hi Ben,

Maybe you could answer this question for me.  I'm reading a book the repeatedly refers to a "bubble" in housing prices. 

What is the technical definition of a bubble?  It sounds as though the price of something is greater than its value.  But I thought that the value of something is what people are willing to pay for it and, as such,  I don't understand how the  price of something can be higher than its value.

Wouldn't another way of looking at the big increase/decrease of the price of a particular is it used to be worth much more and now it is worth much less?

Thanks,
D
_________________

Hi D,

Sorry for taking so long to respond. I am in los Angeles this week for my brother's wedding and things have been pretty hectic. This is a very good question. I used to discuss bubbles in my finance class at Colgate. I promise a fuller answer after I return to Seattle next week. But the quick version is that these are investment assets and not pure consumption goods. Assets provide a stream of consumption over time. So its value at any time depends on people's beliefs about the future. I'll write in more detail next week.

Have a good weekend.

Ben

_________________

Hi D,

Here's the fuller explanation that I promised. When I said a house is an asset that provides a stream of consumption over time, [...] what I meant was that a house provides shelter not just this year, but in
future years as well. In that sense, a house is like an apple tree that yields an apple each year for many years. Houses, apple trees, refrigerators and cars are all examples of assets, because they are long lived and provide a stream of benefit (consumption) over time.

The correct price of an apple tree is, loosely speaking, the sum of the prices of apples that it will provide over time. But the future price of apples is not known for certain today. So we have to make a guess about the future. If apples will be expensive in the future, then apple trees should cost more. If apples will be cheap in the
future, then apple trees should cost less. This need to guess about the future opens the door to incorrect prices. The price of an apple is never wrong because it simply reflects values and tastes (as you had noted). But the price of an apple tree could be wrong because the apple tree contains future apples and we don't know for sure what the prices of apples will be tomorrow. We might pay a lot for an apple tree thinking that apples will be very expensive tomorrow. But when tomorrow comes around, we may find that that apples aren't quite that
expensive, and so we overpaid for that apple tree. In other words, the apple tree was a bad investment.

Just being wrong about the future, however, does not imply a bubble. Nobody can perfectly predict what apples will cost tomorrow. The term bubble implies a more egregious sort of error: assets are being overpriced relative to our expectations about the value of the future services provided by the asset. In other words, apple trees are
selling for more than what people think apples will cost in the future. If you ask people what apples will cost in the future, they say a dollar. But they buy an apple tree for millions of dollars. If you ask them why they are doing this, they say the apple tree will become even more expensive in the future. In other words, people are
buying at an inflated price because they think the inflated price will become even more inflated in the future. The price of the asset has lost touch with the value of the consumption that the asset provides.

For a house, the underlying service provided is shelter in this and future years. The price of that shelter is the cost of renting that house in this year and future years. So the price of the house today should (loosely speaking) equal the cost of renting that house forever. When the price of the house becomes greater than the rent people expect that house to command, we have a bubble. By that calculus, I don't think we have a bubble in housing prices right now. Prices of houses are reasonably aligned with rents on the Eastside at
least, which is where we are looking right now. [Note: In my post of 2/28/2013, I referred to house prices as a bubble. That was loose talk. House prices are artificially inflated by the Fed's policies, but that still doesn't make it a bubble.]

Let me know if you have any more questions. This is a fascinating topic.

Ben

_________________

Very interesting.

It seems that you require there to be rents to determine if housing prices have a bubble or not.  However, I get the impression from some economists that there might be a bubble even if *both* housing prices and rents are high, no?  (And what is "high"?  Today's high might be tomorrow's low.)
__________________

There cannot be a bubble in rents for the reason that you described:
it's simply the value of the service being provided. One cannot
speculate by renting a house, any more than one can speculate by
eating an apple. If people are saying there's a bubble in rents, they
may be using the term bubble in a loose sense to mean that rents are
temporarily high and will go down in the future (what you had
originally proposed). I would not refer to that as a bubble.

Rents tomorrow may be higher or lower than today's rents. No way to be
sure. One can only guess.

There can be a bubble if both housing prices and CURRENT rents are
high, if FUTURE rents are expected to be low. By high and low, I just
mean relative to each other. A numerical example might help. An asset
that provides a service that is worth X dollars a year forever, should
have a price X/r where r is the interest rate. So if you have a
constant real interest rate of 3%, and a house that will rent every
year for $2,500 real dollars per month net of maintenance (so $30,000
real dollars per year), the price should be $30,000/.03=$1 million. If
the house is priced more than that, it is too expensive. If it's less
than that, it is too cheap. This of course is a highly simplified
model that makes a lot of assumptions (constant real interest rate of
3%, constant real rents of $2500, no taxes, etc.). But I hope it gives
you a general sense of the calculation.


0 Comments

Hoarding Cabbage in Beijing

12/11/2013

0 Comments

 
Every winter, elderly Beijingers, scarred by the famines they experienced under Communist planning, stockpile the cabbage that sustained them in the 1950s and 60s. From the New York Times article, As Winter Nears, China is Blanketed in Green:
“When you see a mound of cabbage outside your front door, you feel confident that you won’t starve to death during the winter,” said Wang Jianrong, 62, a retired government worker standing proudly beside a heap of white-and-jade roughage.

In a city crowded with BMWs, upscale malls and produce-packed supermarkets, the stockpiling of cabbage is a vestigial impulse that speaks to an era of scarcity that still haunts Chinese of a certain age.

Older Beijingers vividly recall the hungry winters of the 1950s and ’60s, especially after Mao Zedong’s disastrous attempt to industrialize the nation during the Great Leap Forward, when state-rationed turnips, leeks and cabbage sustained millions. “Back when I was a kid, you never saw a fat person,” said Yang Renzhi, 60, a retired math teacher who was buying three dozen heads for her parents.

The hoarding begins in earnest each November, when farmers from the outskirts of the capital deliver tons of newly harvested cabbage to city sidewalks for a state-sanctioned sale. The green mountains draw armies of gray-haired bargain hunters, who squeeze and prod the vegetables with the intensity of a wizened diamond trader.

“Give me 200 jin of your crispest heads,” Zhang Libao, a 72-year-old former factory worker, barked one recent morning as Li Xueqing, a cabbage grower, loaded up the equivalent of 220 pounds on the back of a flatbed tricycle.

.......

Even as they scoff at the hoarding, younger Beijingers are often forced to indulge their elders, many of whom rarely get through their cabbage reserves and are forced to throw out the moldering, mushy remains come spring.

0 Comments

    Ben Mathew

    Author of Economics: The Remarkable Story of How the Economy Works

    Archives

    October 2016
    September 2016
    February 2016
    November 2015
    September 2015
    July 2015
    June 2015
    May 2015
    March 2015
    February 2015
    December 2014
    November 2014
    October 2014
    September 2014
    July 2014
    June 2014
    May 2014
    April 2014
    March 2014
    February 2014
    January 2014
    December 2013
    November 2013
    October 2013
    September 2013
    August 2013
    July 2013
    June 2013
    May 2013
    April 2013
    March 2013
    February 2013

    Categories

    All

    RSS Feed

Powered by Create your own unique website with customizable templates.